Introduction
On April 2, 2025—what President Donald Trump declared "Liberation Day"—the U.S. government imposed sweeping tariffs on imports from virtually every trading partner. The move included a flat 10% tariff and higher rates of 34% for China and 46% for Vietnam. The global economy reacted swiftly: stock markets plunged, trade partners threatened retaliation, and supply chains trembled under pressure.
For many, this was a déjà vu of the 2018 trade war, which brought higher consumer prices, weak gains in manufacturing, and enduring trade deficits. In today's more fragile economic context, the consequences could be more severe.
This article explores why tariffs fail to deliver on their promises, their broader impact on the global economy, and what a smarter path forward looks like—particularly for African economies.
The Macroeconomic Illusion: Why Tariffs Don’t Fix Trade Deficits
The argument for tariffs often hinges on the idea that they reduce trade deficits and strengthen domestic industries. But this belief misunderstands how national economies work. The belief that tariffs reduce trade deficits is rooted in a flawed interpretation of the national income identity. The starting point is the national income identity:
Y = C + I + G + (X – M) (1)
Where Y is GDP, C consumption, I investment, G government spending, and (X−M) net exports. Rearranging terms, we derive:
(X – M) = S – I (2)
Where which shows that the trade deficit equals the excess of national savings over investment. Including the fiscal balance, the identity becomes:
(X – M) = (Sp – I) + (T-G) (3)
Where (Sp – T) is private savings. This extended identity reveals that trade deficits are manifestations of both private and public sector imbalances (Obstfeld & Rogoff, 1996).
As economist Jeffrey Sachs noted in 2019, "You can't fix the trade deficit with tariffs. It's a macro problem, not a trade policy problem." Unless national savings increase or investment falls, tariffs won't improve the trade balance. In most cases, they simply shift burdens: consumers pay more, inflation rises, and currency adjustments offset any temporary gains (Amiti et al., 2019).
A more accurate diagnosis of persistent trade deficits points to imbalances in national savings and investment. This is captured more directly in the identity in equation 2.
Thus, a country that spends more than it saves will inevitably run a current account deficit, regardless of trade policy. Tariffs do little to alter this reality unless accompanied by structural reforms that improve national savings—through fiscal consolidation, better public investment, and increased private sector savings. In fact, imposing tariffs without addressing these fundamentals may worsen the situation by driving up domestic prices and eroding real incomes. Now let us turn to the balance of payments.
The balance of payments is divided into two primary components: the current account (CA) and the capital/financial account (KA). These are linked through the fundamental accounting identity:
CA + KA = 0 (4)
This identity implies that a current account deficit must be matched by a capital account surplus, which is typically financed by foreign capital inflows. For instance, in 2024, the United States ran a current account deficit of $1.1 trillion, offset by significant foreign purchases of U.S. equities, bonds, and real estate assets (BEA, 2025).
Although the current account is often viewed as a passive outcome of broader economic forces, it can also serve as a strategic anchor for macroeconomic policy coordination. It functions both as a diagnostic tool and a guide for structural reforms.
Improving the current account requires a multipronged approach. Increasing private savings is essential and can be achieved by incentivizing long-term retirement savings, reducing consumption-driven fiscal transfers, and addressing underlying income inequality. Simultaneously, reducing public deficits through progressive tax reforms and the elimination of unproductive government spending can contribute to a more sustainable external position. Efficient investment allocation is also critical—redirecting capital from speculative assets to productivity-enhancing sectors strengthens the supply side of the economy and supports long-term growth.
While the current account is not a policy instrument in the narrow sense, it can be indirectly influenced through well-coordinated reforms. Historical examples, such as Germany and the Nordic countries, demonstrate the use of current account surplus targets as frameworks to inform wage policy, foster savings, and enhance national competitiveness (Obstfeld & Rogoff, 1996).
In the U.S. context, persistent current account deficits reflect deep-rooted macroeconomic imbalances. Attempts to narrow the trade deficit without corresponding fiscal reform are likely to prove unsustainable. The capital account surpluses that finance these deficits have historically led to asset bubbles, currency overvaluation, and a weakening of industrial competitiveness—ultimately exacerbating the very issues that protectionist policies claim to address.
A comprehensive macroeconomic strategy must, therefore, integrate current account monitoring as a key indicator of sustainability. This entails coordinating fiscal and monetary policy to enable meaningful exchange rate adjustment, while also investing in export capacity and enhancing supply-side responsiveness. Only through such an approach can economies raise trade elasticities and satisfy the conditions of the Marshall-Lerner theorem.
Markets React: Volatility in Real Time
The financial response to Trump's 2025 tariffs was swift and severe. The S&P 500 fell more than 11% in a matter of days. The Nasdaq dropped nearly 19% year-to-date. Global indices like the MSCI World Index tumbled 7%, while U.S. futures fell over 1,200 points overnight.
Major institutions including JPMorgan and Goldman Sachs revised global GDP forecasts downward. The IMF (2025) warned of heightened recession risks. Investors shed shares in tech and manufacturing, underscoring just how vulnerable global markets are to protectionist policies.
Who Actually Pays? The Domestic Cost of Tariffs
Despite claims that foreign adversaries bear the burden of tariffs, the reality is that domestic consumers and businesses pay the price. A widely cited study by Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein (2019) showed that tariffs imposed in 2018 were almost entirely passed on to U.S. consumers through higher prices.
Tariffs also hurt American producers who rely on imported parts and materials. Retaliation by trade partners further damages export industries. In 2018, American farmers lost major markets like China and required a $28 billion bailout (Fajgelbaum et al., 2020). Similar interventions may be necessary again in 2025.
The Reshoring Myth: Can Tariffs Bring Jobs Back?
President Trump has long claimed that tariffs would bring offshored manufacturing jobs back to the United States. But the evidence tells a different story. While a few companies have returned some operations stateside, most global supply chains remain deeply entrenched.
In fact, tariffs often prompt firms to relocate production to other low-cost countries rather than return to the U.S. (Irwin, 2019). Moreover, without addressing structural challenges like labor costs and regulatory burdens, reshoring is unlikely to be economically viable. Instead of job creation, we see automation and supply chain rerouting—not revitalized American manufacturing.
Africa at a Crossroads: Navigating the Global Fallout
Developing countries, especially in Africa, face significant risks from global protectionism. Many African economies rely on imported capital goods and intermediate inputs essential for industrialization. Global tariff hikes reduce demand, push down commodity prices, and disrupt regional supply chains.
Equally troubling is the potential for African leaders to emulate U.S.-style protectionism. Such a shift could undermine the African Continental Free Trade Area (AfCFTA), which is key to unlocking regional integration and prosperity.
A Smarter Strategy: Africa’s Path to Prosperity
Tariffs are no substitute for smart policy. Africa's economic future depends on openness, strategic investment, and regional cooperation. Here are eleven expanded recommendations for African countries to pursue:
1. Invest in innovation and human capital: African governments should increase funding for education, science, and technology, and create partnerships with universities and private firms to foster innovation. This includes vocational training and digital literacy to prepare workers for jobs in modern sectors like digital services, renewable energy, and agribusiness.
2. Upgrade infrastructure and logistics: Investments in transport corridors, energy grids, and broadband infrastructure will lower production and transaction costs. Governments should prioritize cross-border infrastructure and public-private partnerships that improve port efficiency and rural connectivity.
3. Reform fiscal and investment policies: Countries should streamline tax systems and reduce regulatory burdens to make them more business-friendly. Offering targeted incentives for green technologies, manufacturing, and tech startups can attract both domestic and foreign investors.
4. Deploy smart subsidies: Governments should offer temporary, performance-based support to promising sectors. These subsidies must include exit strategies and accountability mechanisms to ensure efficiency and competitiveness.
5. Strengthen AfCFTA implementation: Harmonizing standards, digitizing customs, and reducing non-tariff barriers will maximize the gains from intra-African trade. National strategies should align with AfCFTA goals to build resilient, interconnected economies.
6. Enable free movement of people: Ratifying and operationalizing the AU Protocol on Free Movement of Persons and abolishing visa requirements for intra-African travel can enhance labor mobility, promote knowledge transfer, and stimulate investment across borders.
7. Stabilize exchange rates and explore currency harmonization: Central banks should coordinate policies to limit exchange rate volatility and lay the groundwork for a future common currency. Preconditions include macroeconomic convergence, institutional credibility, and regional consensus.
8. Fix macro fundamentals and address the current account: Policymakers must tackle the root causes of external imbalances by boosting national savings, reducing budget deficits, and improving public investment efficiency. The current account should be treated as a macroeconomic barometer that guides fiscal and trade policy decisions.
9. Leverage digital transformation and emerging technologies: Countries should invest in frontier technologies like artificial intelligence, the Internet of Things (IoT), and blockchain to enhance productivity and service delivery. Policymakers must also promote digital entrepreneurship and build regulatory environments that support tech ecosystems.
10. Promote digital integration and telecommunications interoperability: Removing roaming charges and promoting interoperability of mobile and internet services will lower communication costs, improve connectivity, and strengthen regional digital trade. Cross-border digital infrastructure and common regulatory frameworks can enable seamless commerce and collaboration.
11. Engage in global and South-South dialogue: Africa must strengthen its voice in global trade negotiations and expand alliances across the Global South. Strategic partnerships with countries in Latin America, Asia, and the Middle East can diversify markets and reduce reliance on traditional trading partners.
Conclusion: The Real Route to Prosperity
Tariffs may offer short-term political gains, but they do not build lasting economic strength. For developing countries, especially in Africa, the costs of protectionism are steep and the rewards elusive.
Africa must reject economic nationalism and embrace a Pan-African future founded on trade, investment, mobility, and regional solidarity. Strategic reforms can turn today’s global uncertainty into an opportunity for self-defined, inclusive development.
References:
Amiti, M., Redding, S., & Weinstein, D. (2019). "The Impact of the 2018 Trade War on U.S. Prices and Welfare." NBER Working Paper No. 25672.
Sachs, J. D. (2019). Interview on Trade and the U.S. Economy. Columbia University.
Fajgelbaum, P. D., Goldberg, P. K., Kennedy, P. J., & Khandelwal, A. K. (2020). "The Return to Protectionism." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 135(1), 1–55.
Irwin, D. A. (2019). Free Trade Under Fire (5th ed.). Princeton University Press.
IMF. (2025). World Economic Outlook.
MarketWatch and Wall Street Journal. (April 2025).
I don't understand anything I just read.
Great and thought-provoking article.